LAWMALL |
- Updated C.V. or Resume of Attorney Carl E. Person
- Candidates, Elections, Ballot Initiatives, NYC/Town Attorney General
- My Other Politically-Oriented Websites
- My Antitrust Websites and Book
- My Prosecutorial Abuse and Criminal Law Websites
- Additional Websites for Attorneys and Small Law Firms
- Additional Websites for Small Business
- Miscellaneous Websites
- My 6 Self-Help Pamphlets
- My 3 Paperback Books
- 19 Articles for My Losers Magazine
- My Press Releases
- 11/05/07 Lawmall Index Page - to Compare
Carl E. Person
225 E. 36th St Suite 3A
New York NY 10016-3664
Tel. No. - 212-307-4444
Fax No. - 212-307-0247
Email Address: carlpers2@gmail.com
Here are links to two YouTube 1-hour interviews I had recently with Harold Channer.
Carl E. Person and Harold Channer - Air date: 02-28-08 - CLICK ON IMAGE BELOW
Carl E. Person and Harold Channer - Air date: 05-15-08 - CLICK ON IMAGE BELOW
rev 9/1/12
Allegations and Proposed Reform by Wallace H. Kuralt, Owner of the Famous, 40-Year Old, But Now-Failed Bookstore Chain
1st Published on 3/13/02; Date of Last Revision: 3/14/02 at 09:00 am
A NATIONAL DISASTER: THE WAL-MARTS AND MEGA-MALLS IN AMERICA, THE DAMAGES CAUSED BY
THEM AND THE FACTORS USED BY THEM TO DISPEL COMPETITION, WITH APPROACHES TO SOLUTIONS.
By Wallace Kuralt, March 13, 2002.
The Wal-Mart, the mega-mall, the "big box" center full of "category killer" national chain stores - all seem to excite great enthusiasm on the part of city and county officials and their planners. That's where the big money would seem to be.
Yet experience and the widely-respected Shils Report from the Wharton School tell us that it is all smoke and mirrors. Is there hope for a solution? Read on.
The "down side" of the Wal-Marts and the mega-malls
- The finished project turns out to have less value than the developers had originally estimated, resulting in lower property tax income for the municipality - and even these values are disputed.
- The highway development which must be funded for proper traffic management costs many millions, little of it paid by the developers.
- Developers are given large incentives in the form of short-term tax breaks, rezoning, planning funds, special access to planners and even cash.
- The project is typically sold to another management group shortly after the grand opening.
- Jobs that are created are mostly low-pay, part-time and "temp" or "contract" positions offering little in the way of benefits, retirement plans, advancement or job security.
- The companies that hire these staffers have in place a well-managed plan for defeating unemployment claims, with outside attorneys to appear at hearings to dispute every claim - usually with success.
- The developments drive other area enterprises out of business, due to perceived better shopping environments with lower prices and other customer amenities, such as free parking, easy access, new construction, new stores, better locations and more.
- The area businesses which are lost are largely in downtown areas and earlier shopping center.
- Many of the businesses which are lost are in another county.
- Those lost businesses tend to create a "gap-toothed" look in the old shopping area, further accelerating the exodus of other businesses and creating a feeling of decay and lack of safety.
- The old, local businesses had created a social environment typical of small business, in which each contributed in its own business area to a relatively safe "completeness" which made it a social center as well as a business center. These small businesses tended to be quite responsive to the community, supporting local arts, sports and charity efforts, and hiring and training local youngsters, as well as helping develop a strong, full-time staff. The more successful of them provided benefits such as vacation pay, paid holidays, sick pay, contributions to health insurance, life insurance, retirement plans and unemployment insurance, not offered by the larger companies.
- The old, local businesses were also more responsive to customers seeking assistance, both before and after the sale, and many took great pains to see that their customers were fully satisfied. They also provided extra service in shipping, repairing, replacing faulty merchandise and even delivering. They were managed largely by the owners on site, and could be far more efficient and effective in managing their inventory and costs, and could therefore operate at lower expense.
- As businesses leave an area in a state of decay, crime tends to move in rapidly, creating additional costs to the municipality.
- The funds created for the municipality can hardly offset the losses of property taxes and sales tax revenues, lost when the sales formerly made by existing stores are simply snatched away by the new enterprise. Little in the way of "new" revenues are created, most simply being transfers from one retailer to another, larger one.
- The funds lost by the adjoining municipalities are not replaced at all.
- Local, state and federal funds are heavily employed to help create newer and larger transportation facilities to the new enterprises and to upgrade utilities in the area of the new center.
The "DNA" factors favoring the national chains
Now add to the mix the fact that many, if not most, of the national business chains solicit and receive discriminatory prices from their suppliers, using their "buying power," or "muscle," to force extra discounts, fees, rebates, terms, free goods, special advertising allowances and "slotting fees," much of it in violation of the anti-trust provisions of the Robinson-Patman Act.
In papers recently filed in federal court in New York, it can be seen that the national chain bookstores are receiving discriminatory prices such that they buy at 35%-40% of "list" price, whereas their smaller competitors are buying at about 60% of list price! This for the same goods in the same quantities and quality at the same time.
Each of the benefits available in a discriminatory manner to the chains helps make up the DNA Code of business which spells success for the chains over their other competitors. Those with the strongest DNA linkages have success even over their large competitors.
This means that a chain can make 60% or 65% gross profit from most of its suppliers, more than half again that of the smaller stores on the same goods. This permits the chains to discount heavily, to advertise and promote heavily, to build expensive buildings in expensive locations - and still make more gross profit than their competitors.
Some of the discriminatory payments and benefits received by the chains - and largely not disputed by the chains - are listed below. Each is a part of the "price" paid for merchandise received.
Some of the aspects of "price"
- Discounted retail price, as shown on the invoice.
- Extra discount, whether shown on invoice or not.
- Freight allowances
- Freight allowances beyond stated terms
- "Co-op" funds allowed
- "Co-op" funds exceeding costs of advertising
- Special discounts for the initial stock of books ordered
- Special discounts for initial stock, though not offered to others
- Free books
- Free books not offered to others
- Free freight
- Free freight, though not offered to others
- Extra "dating" in paying the bills
- Extra "dating" in paying the bills, though not offered to others
- Extra co-op advertising funds to help the grand opening
- Extra co-op advertising funds to help the grand opening, though not offered others
- Special allowances for fixtures
- Special allowances for fixtures, though not offered to others
- Special author appearances to help promote the grand opening
- Extra discounts, for retail distribution center (RDC)
- Extra discounts, for (RDC), though not offered to others
- Allowances to cover re-shipping from the RDC to the retail stores
- "Statistical allowance," fee applied for presumed errors in shipping, without having to verify and claim each instance, whether offered to others or not
- Extra fee for returns consolidation, whether offered to others or not
- Extra incentives for keeping purchases high, whether offered to others or not
- Extra incentives for keeping returns low, whether offered to others or not
- "Special deals," whether offered to others or not
- Access to "shared markdowns," whether offered to others or not
- Access to remainders whether offered to others or not
- Access to "hurt" books whether offered to others or not
- Large "settlements" of payables, favoring certain purchasers, whether offered to others or not
- Cash discounts for payment, whether offered to others or not
- Special "check-swapping" procedures, whether offered to others or not
- Special services, such as special carton-marking, whether offered to others or not
- Special services, such as early shipping of important titles, whether offered to others or not
- Extended terms taken by defendants, without having shipments "held," whether offered to others or not
- Special terms such that chains never actually own any merchandise, not offered to others
- Use of chargebacks taken for co-op, rather than normal terms, whether offered to others or not
- Co-op granted without verification of service, whether offered to others or not
- Disguising of freight charges, whether offered to others or not
- Payments for purchaser's sales information, whether offered to others or not
- Access to information regarding competitors, whether offered to others or not
- Much special attention from sales reps, whether offered to others or not
- Special access to publishing officials, whether offered to others or not
- Allowing huge returns without penalty, whether offered to others or not
- Allowing fraudulent chargebacks to be made without penalty, whether offered to others or not
- Special (unauthorized) large discounts for early payment, without requiring that they be repaid, whether offered to others or not
- Reserving inventory of certain titles for the chain, not offered to independents
- Special publication of titles exclusively for the chain store
- "Trade acceptances," offered to chains and not to independents - a no-interest, no-pay line of credit
- And more.
Going, going, gone!
These discriminatory payments, fees, rebates, chargebacks, allowances, free services such as freight, special shipping arrangements, free merchandise -- and more, still being uncovered and exposed to the public - amount to as much as one-third of the invoice "price," and permit the chains simply to expand at will and overwhelm any smaller competition, even though the chains are notoriously inefficient and even though these payments give in return very little benefit to the supplier, other than assuring that their products will be given shelf space in the store.
Competitors are forced to discount in order to compete - even though their profit margins are tiny compared to those of the chains. They must spend money to advertise and promote, must try to give better service, find a special niche for themselves, have a large stock of goods or items not yet discovered by the chains, or open in a location far from the chain stores. All to often the chain simply co-opts the business after the smaller competitor has created a demand for a certain product or line of goods.
The customers of the chain stores are happy to purchase merchandise at prices often far lower than those of the chains' competitors, and care little that almost no service is offered to the customer. There is little or no assistance in finding merchandise, in explaining how it is to be used, in repairing damaged or faulty goods, or in shipping or delivering or gift-wrapping the merchandise. Returns can be made only by waiting in long lines.
The chain stores vary their prices in each location according to the strength of the competition. After the competition is effectively silenced, the chains are free to charge whatever they wish, even though the competitors were vanquished by acts in violation of the law.
Customers of the chains - who never meet the owner or any responsible official - realize that complaining is useless. They can accept matters as they are or go elsewhere. Sellers to the chains understand that they must give in to the demands of the chains or try to make a living selling to the disfavored competitors of the chains, many of which have failed. Many of the suppliers fail, too - snuffing out any hope of innovative improvements and new products from those sources. The supply of competing products dwindles to those accepted by the chains.
Approaches to Solutions
The municipality that spends its development money wooing the mega-mall and the mega-store does so in the spirit of stealing a march on its "competitors," the counties around it. The residents of those counties drive to the new business center on roads maintained by the disfavored county and bypass the existing stores in their own areas, and all of the income of sales taxes accrues to the benefit of the "favored" county.
The competition is sometimes fierce, especially when the development is also close to a state border. The adjacent counties or states have little or no control over the officials of the favored county and its officials, yet stand to suffer heavy losses in their own municipalities if the other county "wins" the "prize." It seems sensible - and only fair - that the benefits now enjoyed exclusively by the "winning" county be allocated on a proportional basis according to the home addresses of the customers and employees of the new business center.
Such a system would have to take into account the relatively high expense of servicing the center incurred by the host county, but would provide a fair contribution to the costs of the surrounding counties, as well.
Many retailers now note the zip code of the customer when making the sale. Using these numbers, or those collected by a scientific random sampling of the shoppers from time to time, officials could spread the largesse over all affected municipalities.
The idea of employing the "use" tax, though this tax be somewhat more difficult to implement and maintain, could also be examined as a means of making equitable the benefits produced by the new center, if only to encourage the counties to co-operate in using revenue-sharing.
Certainly the decision to share the funds would dampen to some extent the zeal of the local officials in spending their good money in seeking to accommodate the developers in the first place.
Too, local officials should demonstrate the concern for the safety and well-being of their constituents by examining the operations of the developer and the companies which the developer proposes to invite into the development. This should be done as thoroughly as is the control exerted over companies whose operations or products might pollute the environment or of persons known to be sex offenders or drug dealers. Licenses should be refused those who decline to co-operate in making public their activities in regard to fair competition and Robinson-Patman Act matters.
The path of a Robinson-Patman Act legal action is a long and twisting one, and such action is expensive to undertake and maintain by private civil action. The proper forum for such examination is that of the official public inquiry. State laws, however, tend to cede action regarding unfair competition to the federal jurisdiction, and federal officials such as the Justice Department and the Federal Trade Commission are noted for their lack of accepting responsibility in such cases.
This leaves the matter to individual companies - class actions are felt to be unacceptable by the federal courts. This is quite a burden for any company, especially if it is small and has already been heavily damaged.
However, it is not impossible for a legal action to be prosecuted, though great care and expertise must be employed to achieve success. Please see other papers in this site concerning The Intimate Bookshop vs Barnes & Noble et al and other actions undertaken by Carl Person's firm regarding the distribution of auto parts and of magazine distribution.
The Shils Report is also available in its entirety in Mr. Person's web site. See The Famous Shils Report and also see the following related website:
- RPAMall - Robinson-Patman Act Mall
- Website on Wallace Kuralt's RPA Action against Barnes & Noble and Borders
- Website on How to Stop Wal-Mart and Other Superstore Chains from Opening Up New Stores in any Community; and Stopping Aspects of Globalization
- How Enron Can Be Viewed as a Good Thing for the United States
Future Shock?
What, then, might be the result if all national chain store companies were required to observe the law?
- Retailing would become considerably more competitive, relying upon smart merchandising and value.
- The chains would have to accept the seller's price, as offered, or decline to purchase the merchandise - unless the seller were to choose to offer the same item to all purchasers at the same lower price.
- Certainly purchases of large quantities could command a somewhat better discount, as justified by any cost saving to the seller, perhaps as much as three or four percentage points.
- All advertising allowances would be made proportionately equal, according to the amount purchased.
- Even the smallest purchaser would be given advertising benefits which it could reasonably be able to use, or some other form of the benefit would be given, instead.
- Local media would benefit from the advertising funds made available to the local merchants, and would be more interested in their operations.
- The chain stores already have the advantage of numbers and locations, and would continue to draw large numbers of customers by virtue of their large stores and selections, if they chose to maintain them at their own expense.
- Many more manufacturers and suppliers would become profitable, and would contribute to the variety available in the market.
- Goods would be marketed according to their quality, usefulness and innovation, rather than merely upon price, providing incentive for manufacturers and suppliers to be creative and productive.
- Many more manufacturers and suppliers would find their goods in demand, as many more outlets opened up to offer them at retail.
- Downtown locations would once again be in demand by retailers who would have the capacity to compete with each other and with the chains.
- Developers would be unable to command the extremely high rental amounts now being collected, and this would dampen enthusiasm to build or even to own such facilities.
- Counties that had vied for developers' favor would, instead, turn their attention to the development of local businesses and their owners.
- More jobs would be created, more salaries paid, more sales made and more products made available in competition with each other.
Sailing in All Directions
It is said that "Tranquil seas never made an expert mariner." Real competition produces real successes. In the late 1800s and early 1900s, when various "trusts" ruled much of American commerce - in steel, coal, railroading and more - the trust were protected from competition from abroad by heavy tariffs provided by the American congress. President Wilson, at great political risk, defied the trusts and their lobbies, and pledged in his campaign to drop most of the tariffs. This was necessary, he felt, if we were to be sure that American companies would be able to compete - fairly - anywhere in the world.
The "anti-trust" laws came into being, largely concerned with heavy industry and large companies. In 1936 the Robinson-Patman Act was made into law in order to protect the smaller companies, especially the retailers, from the emerging department stores.
But a law is useful only if those responsible for enforcing it have the will and the funding with which to do so. The RPA has not been enforced by public officials, and only the federal judiciary stands in the way of outright predatory and destructive behavior by the larger national retailing companies. Those who argue for "free" trade and unfettered business activity are invariably those who have the capacity to control a market simply by virtue of their financial capacity, without regard to business acumen.
With the world rapidly trending to international trade, American retailing and merchandising has fallen under the control of those who believe that the muscle of its capital is its only needed asset or virtue, and its ship is sinking rapidly. The time has come to take the restraints from the manufacturers and wholesalers and distributors and allow retailing to become once again truly competitive.
American manufacturers, hobbled by the power of the national chains, have sent millions of jobs to offshore sites in order to obtain goods at the lowest possible cost, without regard to the damage such acts cause in their own country. Smaller companies have been forced to merge, causing huge losses of jobs in the home areas of those companies.
Smaller retailers have closed by the tens of thousands, all because the playing field has been permitted to tilt so advantageously in the direction of the large companies who ignore the law. The social structure of thousands of small towns has been shattered, as local business owners are forced, in shame, to quit.
The time to act is now. The Robinson-Patman Act and other fair-trade laws must be upgraded and enforced. Those who stand to benefit so inequitably must be required to stand and compete instead of relying upon the use of "muscle" in contradiction to law.
The American manufacturer and retailer must once again be made an important part of the business system, however small they may be, so that our strength can once again be that of innovation, effective marketing and merchandising, rather than the strength of illegal intimidation.
The American ship must be able to sail in any direction, regardless of the seas against it, to deliver and bring home cargoes of pride and success.
WHK